Approval voting

From Ballotpedia
Jump to: navigation, search



Election Policy Logo.png

Electoral system
Electoral systems by state
Ranked-choice voting (RCV)
Academic studies on RCV
Election dates
Election agencies
Election terms

Ballotpedia's Election Administration Legislation Tracker

Public Policy Logo-one line.png

Approval voting is an electoral system in which voters may vote for any number of candidates they choose. The candidate receiving the most votes wins. Approval voting may be used in single-winner systems and multi-winner systems.

As of June 2021, approval voting had been implemented in two U.S. cities for local elections: Fargo, North Dakota, and St. Louis, Missouri.

Use

This section provides information on jurisdictions that had implemented approval voting as of June 2021.

Fargo, North Dakota

Voters in Fargo approved Measure 1 in November 2018, 63.5% to 36.5%. The measure implemented approval voting in local elections beginning in 2020.

St. Louis, Missouri

In November 2020, St. Louis voters approved Proposition D, 68.15% to 31.85%. The measure implemented approval voting in local primary elections beginning in 2021.

What approval voting looks like

See also: Mayoral election in St. Louis, Missouri (March 2, 2021, top-two primary)

This section shows how approval voting unfolded in St. Louis' top-two mayoral primary election.

In the mayoral primary, 44,571 people voted and cast 69,661 total votes—an average of 1.56 votes per ballot.[1]

  • Tishaura Jones was selected on 25,388 ballots. Fifty-seven percent (57%) of voters selected her on their ballots, and she received 36% of the total number of votes cast.
  • Cara Spencer was selected on 20,659 ballots, coming in second. She was picked on 46% of ballots, and she received 30% of the total votes.

Sample ballot

This sample ballot came from the city's website.[2]

Results

The election results PDF below came from the city's website.[1]

In the June 2020 city commissioner election in Fargo, voters cast an average of 2.28 votes per ballot—42,855 votes across 18,805 ballots.[3]

Arguments for and against approval voting

Support

The Center for Election Science—a nonprofit that advocates for the implementation of approval voting—wrote that the following are advantages of approval voting over plurality voting and ranked-choice voting:[4][5]

  • More expressive
  • Removes vote splitting almost entirely, virtually eliminating spoilers
  • You can never get a worse result by voting for your favorite
  • Significantly fewer spoiled ballots
  • Ballots look the same, except the rules indicate that you may vote for any number of candidates
  • Results are still easy to understand: a simple list of the candidates along with how many votes they received
  • Tends to elect candidates who would beat all rivals head-to-head
  • Tends to elect more consensus winners
  • Alternate candidates get a more accurate measure of support

...
Our extensive analysis over the years overwhelmingly supports the view that Approval Voting is a much simpler and more democratic system than IRV (also referred to as ranked-choice voting, or RCV). The results of approval voting elections are also much easier to understand than the numerous rounds of vote transfers that IRV utilizes. In an approval voting election, you would only see approval percentages and total votes for each candidate — much simpler than IRV.[6]

Tishaura Jones, who won the 2021 mayoral election in St. Louis and was the city's treasurer at the time of the Proposition D vote, said the following:[7]

Ultimately, Proposition D empowers St. Louis voters with more choices and ensures that the next mayor has to win the support of the majority of voters.[6]

Opposition

Rob Richie, president of FairVote—an organization that advocates for the implementation of ranked-choice voting—wrote in 2016:[8]

There are uses of approval voting that can make sense -- like when a group of people deciding on what movie to watch. While mathematicians can like this system and its alleged likelihood of electing a consensus winner, my colleagues and I are highly skeptical of its use in candidate elections. Two factors stand out:

  • Viability and the issue of majority rule: If voters truly are free with their approvals in an approval voting election, it’s quite possible two or more candidates could earn more than half the vote. Indeed, it’s possible that a candidate whom well over half of voters see as a top choice could lose to someone who nobody sees as their top choice. Approval voting advocates defend such outcomes as fair, but it remains to be seen what voters would say.
  • Workability in the real world: In approval voting elections, you can’t indicate support for more than one candidate without support for a lesser choice potentially causing the defeat of your first choice. This transparent dilemma for voters trying to cast a smart vote has immediate consequences. Because most voters as a result of this problem will refrain from approving of more than one candidate, the system in practice ends up looking far more like a plurality voting election system than a majority system.[6]

The African American Aldermanic Caucus wrote of St. Louis' Proposition D:[9]

Proposition D disenfranchises voters, because ballots that do not include the two ultimate finalists are cast aside to manufacture a faux majority for the winner. Under Proposition D, you never really know who will be running against whom in the final vote count with ranked choice. It is all a numbers gimmick.[6]

See also

External links

Footnotes